Up Migration to Make the World Richer

There is a way to make the poor of this world 500 billion dollars better off, but this solution is rarely discussed. This matters, because the international community is gearing up to produce the next set of development goals for 2015-2030, to follow on from the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs).

A 2.5 trillion dollars in development aid plus unknown trillions from national budgets hangs in the balance of these goals so getting our priorities right is vital. Spending money on poor targets is possibly a wasted opportunity to do much more good elsewhere.

To do the most good, the Copenhagen Consensus Centre (CCC), has asked 60 teams of the world’s top economists to look at the economic, social and environmental costs and benefits of all the top targets. Some of these are obvious like health, education, food, water and environment, but some are less so, though often discussed in the development community. One of these is the transfer of technology from rich to poor and middle-income countries as an aid to sustainable development.

The reason technology is so important is that it makes people more productive, so boosting overall economic growth. Not just that but, once knowledge has been gained, it is embedded in society and can be used as a stepping stone for future growth. Countries with a reasonable technical or research and development base are in a better position to absorb and make the best use of more new technologies as they become available.

Keith E. Maskus (Prof.) from University of Colorado, United States, has written an extensive paper on what works and how much good it will do. As he rightly points out, the United Nation’s technology-related targets are simply too general and bland. Instead, using the economic literature, he puts forward two proposals.

The first proposal is straight-forward: if our goal is to get more technology available for the poor, maybe, we should simply increase investment in research and development (R&D), especially in the developing world.

The point is the benefits from R&D do not just go to the company doing it; there are also broader societal benefits as productivity gains occur elsewhere in the economy and other people learn on the job or see the possibility for more innovation. After Apple produced an innovative touch screen on its first iPhone, the knowledge is now available to lots of products in many different areas.

This broader benefit justifies governments supporting research, either through tax credits or direct government spending on research in public institutions. On average, the developing countries spend just 0.2pc of their gross domestic product (GDP) on R&D and perhaps 0.3pc in 2030.

If we instead aim at 0.5pc of GDP by 2030 and 1.5pc for emerging economies, this would naturally increase the direct government costs, but it would also increase the long-run technological innovation and capabilities. For comparison, Ethiopia spends only 0.25pc, so it would need to climb to 0.5pc.

The models estimate in total, that for every dollar spent, we could likely end up doing three dollars worth of good. That is not bad.

However, there is another and much more effective way to increase technological capabilities in low-income countries. Instead of focusing on innovating more technology to make people more productive, we could focus on getting more people to places where they would be productive.

While allowing the free mobility of goods (free trade) can add several percentage points to global GDP, we have long known that free mobility of people could add anywhere from 67pc-147pc to global GDP. Allowing free mobility could essentially double the world’s income.

This is because people in poor areas are not inherently unproductive but their circumstances mostly make them unproductive. So, if they were to migrate, from say, Ethiopia to the European Union (EU), they would become much more productive.

Of course, absolutely free mobility would result in a massive relocation from poor to rich countries, which would likely engender huge political issues. But Maskus suggests that we could start off with a modest goal of increasing current skilled migration by five percent to 20pc with 10-year visas.

An increase in skilled migration could mean about 117,000 more managerial and technical workers, with about half going to the EU, 13,000 to other large economies like Turkey and South Africa, and 50,000 would be crossing borders to work within the African continent. Although other research shows migrants would only become half or less as productive as Europeans and other more productive neighbors, this would still make them much better off.

The model shows they would earn 22 billion dollars more over the next 25 years. Moreover, as they would bring with them new ideas and concepts, they will increase productivity in the EU and elsewhere by 660 million dollars.

Of course, this will also mean an outflow of skilled workers from poorer countries. Maybe 16,000 people will leave Ethiopia for 10 years. But they will send back money – about 940 million dollars in total.

While many worry about a ‘brain drain’, there is actually more evidence for a ‘brain gain’: If there is an opportunity to go abroad and make more money as a doctor or engineer, it will induce more young to invest in a professional education, meaning more doctors and technicians in the long run. And as these skilled professionals come back after 10 years, they will also bring back new ideas and higher productivity.

In total, the costs, mostly in lost tax revenue are significantly outweighed by the gains. For every dollar spent, this target could do 10 dollars to 48 dollars worth of good. The potential benefits could go as high as 500 billion dollars. That should make the target of higher labor mobility a strong contender for the world’s next set of goals.


Posted

in

by

Tags:

Comments

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.